中文题名: | 人力资本配置与工作时间 |
姓名: | |
保密级别: | 公开 |
论文语种: | chi |
学科代码: | 020207 |
学科专业: | |
学生类型: | 博士 |
学位: | 经济学博士 |
学位类型: | |
学位年度: | 2023 |
校区: | |
学院: | |
研究方向: | 劳动经济学 |
第一导师姓名: | |
第一导师单位: | |
提交日期: | 2023-11-04 |
答辩日期: | 2023-09-26 |
外文题名: | Human Capital Allocation and Hours of Work |
中文关键词: | |
外文关键词: | human capital allocation ; working hours ; higher education expansion ; occupational choice ; agglomeration ; COVID-19 |
中文摘要: |
在劳动力规模持续减少的背景下,面对人口红利渐失、劳动力成本上升,要素投入面临更大约束的严峻形势,如何提升人力资本水平并有效配置,有非常重要的意义。已有研究多从教育扩张、工资收入差距、生产率等角度研究人力资本配置问题,而从工作时间的角度看,失业、歇业或工时不足体现出人力资本的闲置,工时过长带来的生命健康危害、生产效率下降和工作家庭冲突造成人力资本不能取得最大回报,地区、职业、部门间的工时差异可能意味着闲暇福利的不平等和人力资本的错配,但国内相关研究由于数据来源的限制,仍十分缺乏。本文建立理论和实证模型,从增量配置角度讨论以受教育水平提高为主的人力资本提升如何影响工作时间;从职业配置角度讨论工时约束和工时过长如何影响不同受教育水平人群的劳动参与和职业选择;从空间配置角度探讨人力资本向城市的迁移和集聚如何影响工作时间的地区差异;最后从部门配置角度探讨劳动力市场外部负向冲击对不同所有制、产业部门劳动者短期失业和工时闲置的异质影响。主要研究结论如下: |
外文摘要: |
Nowadays, with the continuous reduction of the scale of labor force, facing the gradual loss of demographic dividend, the rise of labor cost, and the severe situation of greater factor constraints, how to improve the level of human capital and effectively allocate it is of great significance. Existing research related to human capital allocation, are from the perspective of education expansion, wage income gap and productivity. From the perspective of working time, unemployment, closed or lack of hours reflects the idle human capital; long hours of work results in life and health hazards, productivity reduction and working family conflict, which means human capital cannot achieve the maximum return; regional, occupational, sectoral differences in hours of work means that leisure inequality and the mismatch of human capital; but due to the limitation of data sources, the domestic research is still very lack. This paper establishes both the theoretical and the empirical model, from the perspective of increment allocation, discuss how the improvement of human capital mainly with the improvement of education level affects the working hours; from the perspective of occupational allocation, discuss how time constraints and long hours affect the labor participation and career choice of people with different education levels; from the perspective of spatial allocation, discuss how the migration and agglomeration of human capital to cities affect the regional differences of working hours; finally, the heterogeneous impact of the policy of lockdown and social isolation under the impact of COVID-19 on the short-term unemployment and idle working hours of the workers of different ownership and industrial sectors is discussed. The main study conclusions are summarized as follows: Firstly, the higher the education level of Chinese workers, the shorter their working hours, which applies to various groups of people grouped by gender, age, household registration, and occupation. The weekly working hours of laborers with a bachelor's degree or above are on average 11.9% lower than those with a junior high school education or below, 10.3% lower than those with a high school education, and 4.6% lower than those with a junior college education. In terms of age groups, the difference in working hours between different education levels is smallest in the younger group (22-29 years old) and largest in the older group (40-59 years old). In terms of gender, the reduction in working hours after receiving higher education is significantly greater for women than for men. In terms of household registration status, the difference in working hours between different education levels is greater for non-local residents than for local residents and greater for non-agricultural household registration than for agricultural household registration. Workers with higher education levels not only engage in positions with shorter working hours (defined by industry, occupation, and unit type), but also have shorter working hours in the same job position. In addition, the shorter working hours are due to a decrease in the proportion of excessive working hours rather than an increase in the proportion of insufficient working hours. The proportion of workers with a bachelor's degree or above who work more than 48 hours per week is 31.7% lower than that of workers with a junior high school education or below, 20.0% lower than that of workers with a high school education, and 6.3% lower than that of workers with a junior college education. Under the condition that there is a negative correlation between education level and working hours, measuring wage levels in terms of monthly (annual) income significantly underestimates the rate of return on education, and the hourly wage return on education is significantly higher than the return on monthly income. Secondly, there is a phenomenon of hours constraint in China's labor market. The primary way for workers to adjust their working hours is to switch to different jobs. Married women with higher education levels are more likely to choose professions with shorter working hours or exit the labor market due to family caregiving responsibilities. The proportion of jobs with long working hours has a significant negative impact on the labor participation rate of married women with college degrees or above, as well as their employment share in related occupations. Compared with those who do not need to care for children aged 6 and below, the younger the children that married women need to care for, the greater the negative impact on their labor participation rate. An increase in the proportion of jobs with long working hours will not affect the probability of women employed in related occupations exiting the labor market within one year. However, it will significantly increase the probability of married women with college degrees or above switching to professions with relatively shorter working hours. The impact on the younger group aged 22-39 is greater than that on the older group aged 40-59, and family caregiving burden will amplify its negative impact Thirdly, the difference in working hours between cities is significant and closely related to urbanization (measured by urban population density) and localization (measured by employment population density in the same industry). It is consistent with the expectations of the work-spreading and rat race hypotheses. The elasticity of employee working hours with respect to urban population density is negative, while the elasticity with respect to employment density in the same industry is positive. The lower the level of education, the greater the absolute value of the elasticity coefficient. The young labor force is in the early stage of career development, and work tasks are easier to be shared by homogeneous workers, and they are more likely to participate in rat race under the incentive of promotion. For high school employees, consistent with the prediction of the rat race hypothesis, employees are more likely to share work load with people in the same age group and occupation, and wage gap can motivate workers to work longer, even if there is no competition among homogeneous groups. But for employees in middle school and below, rat race seems to not exist, the reason for increasing working hours is mainly greater income returns. Fourth is the COVID-19 epidemic has also brought about the reconfiguration of human capital between industries in the short term. There may be significant differences in the necessity of working from home among industries, occupations, regions and populations, resulting in less impact on employment in industries that are necessary for supply or can be electronically operated. In contrast, non-essential or contact-intensive industries have experienced idle working hours in the short term, including unemployment, on-the-job suspension and exit from the labor market. The proportion of human capital in non-contact-intensive industries with higher wages has increased, and the efficiency of human capital allocation has decreased, which may expand welfare differences between industrial sectors. Employees of state-owned collective departments and other jobs that are more likely to work from home and engage in necessary industries are more likely to retain their jobs under epidemic control policies and supporting employment protection measures. They are in a state of being employed but not working or working from home. During the epidemic period, their working time investment and wage decline less. Temporary and self-employed workers are more likely to be unemployed or suspended due to losing opportunities such as casual work. The following theoretical and policy implications can be obtained from the research of this paper. One is the education yield measured using wage income and hourly wages will have big difference, based on hourly wage income returns can better measure the improvement of individual welfare, but in our country to pay monthly salary, full-time work lack of hourly wage standard, respectively measure wage income returns and leisure returns has important practical significance. Second, after the implementation of the "universal three-child" policy, the balance between work and life is under greater pressure, which not only affects women's labor participation and career choice behavior during childbirth peak period, but also affects the labor participation and career choice of women in non-childbearing age due to the changing burden of inter-generational care. We should pay attention to the protection of women's labor rights and interests, expand the supply of elderly care services, and encourage enterprises to implement more flexible working hour systems, so as to promote the employment of high-skilled women. Third, the difference in working hours between cities also means that the regional difference of wage income does not necessarily represent the difference in regional welfare. The degree of spatial mismatch of labor resources is greater than the level shown by the surplus wage difference, and the difference in educational return between regions should also consider the contribution of the difference in working hours. The migration of labor to big cities may be due not only to the higher wage income, but also to more leisure. Fourth, human capital allocation should fully consider the ability of different industries, occupations, and populations to respond to external shocks. How digital technology empowers enterprises and workers, especially the rapid development of modern information technologies such as artificial intelligence, and how the "digital divide" between different groups affects workers' employment and their ability to respond to supply-demand shocks need to be highly concerned by policy makers. |
参考文献总数: | 163 |
馆藏地: | 图书馆学位论文阅览区(主馆南区三层BC区) |
馆藏号: | 博020207/23002 |
开放日期: | 2024-11-05 |